1 of 71

A FRAMEWORK FOR THE�FAIR PRICING�OF MEDICINES

Mike Paulden

2 of 71

A FRAMEWORK FOR�THE FAIR PRICING OF MEDICINES

Paulden M

Pharmacoeconomics. 2024;42:145–64

doi.org/10.1007/s40273-023-01325-z

3 of 71

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

I would like to thank Christopher McCabe and James O’Mahony for providing support and critical feedback throughout the development of this framework.

I would also like to thank three anonymous peer-reviewers for providing suggestions for improvements.

4 of 71

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This manuscript builds upon a conceptual framework that I developed as chair of a working group that informed the Canadian Patented Medicine Prices Review Board (PMPRB)’s modernization of its price review process guidelines.

I wish to thank anonymous members of the working group who provided feedback on this conceptual framework.

5 of 71

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This manuscript also builds upon some earlier work that was included in an appendix to a 2018 report by the Institute of Health Economics (IHE) and funded by the PMPRB.

I would like to thank Himani Pandey and Christopher McCabe for co-authoring that report, and the IHE and PMPRB for supporting the research.

6 of 71

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

Finally, I would like to thank the Office of Health Economics (OHE) for supporting the dissemination of this research through their Innovation Policy Prize, and the Canadian Institutes of Health Research (CIHR) for providing grant funding that supported open-access publication.

7 of 71

INTRODUCTION

8 of 71

CONSIDERATION 1:

MEDICINE PRICES HAVE IMPLICATIONS FOR�POPULATION HEALTH

9 of 71

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE�SYSTEM BUDGET

Reimbursement of a�new medicine

$$$

Less funding for other health care�(longer waiting lists, delisting, other�investment opportunities forgone)

$$$

Expected health improvements

10 of 71

CANADIANS DYING WHILE ON MEDICAL WAIT LISTS REACHES FIVE-YEAR HIGH, REPORT FINDS

National Post Staff

National Post. 6 Dec 2023

nationalpost.com/news/canadians-dying-�while-on-medical-wait-lists-reaches-�five-year-high-report-finds

11 of 71

“AS BAD AS WE’VE�SEEN IT IN 25 YEARS”:�AMA PRESIDENT SOUNDS ALARM AS ALBERTA HOSPITAL WAIT TIMES RISE

Carmichael J, Ostad R

Edmonton Journal. 11 Dec 2023

edmontonjournal.com/news/politics/�alberta-wait-times-rise-health-care

12 of 71

ONTARIO HOSPITALS�WARN OF PATIENT SURGES,�LONG WAIT TIMES

Jones A

CBC News. 11 Jan 2024

cbc.ca/news/canada/toronto/ont-ers-1.7081016

13 of 71

NATIONAL SURVEY HIGHLIGHTS WORSENING PRIMARY CARE ACCESS

Duong D, Vogel L

CMAJ. 2023;195:E592–3

doi.org/10.1503/cmaj.1096049

14 of 71

“More than one in five Canadians —�an estimated 6.5 million people — do not have�a family physician or nurse practitioner they�see regularly, according to a national survey.

That’s a dramatic increase since 2019 when�Statistics Canada estimated only 4.5 million people�did not have a regular health care provider.”

15 of 71

Expected health improvements

Expected health losses

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE�SYSTEM BUDGET

Reimbursement of a�new medicine

$$$

Less funding for other health care�(longer waiting lists, delisting, other�investment opportunities forgone)

$$$

16 of 71

Expected health improvements

Expected health losses

Under a publicly-funded health system perspective, the purpose of a health economic evaluation is to consider the expected impact on the overall health of the population

Focus is population health,�not other considerations such as productivity

17 of 71

Expected health improvements

Expected health losses

At a low price, reimbursing an effective medicine will�improve the overall health of the population

18 of 71

Expected health improvements

Expected health losses

At a high price, reimbursing an effective medicine will�diminish the overall health of the population

19 of 71

CONSIDERATION 2:

MEDICINE R&D AND MANUFACTURING IS EXPENSIVE

20 of 71

ESTIMATED RESEARCH�AND DEVELOPMENT INVESTMENT NEEDED TO BRING A NEW MEDICINE�TO MARKET, 2009-2018

Wouters OJ, McKee M, Luyten J

JAMA. 2020;323:844–53

doi.org/10.1001/jama.2020.1166

21 of 71

A STARTING POINT

As a starting point, the framework proposes�that a ‘fair’ price for a medicine is one that is:

1. Low enough that reimbursing the medicine�is expected to improve population health

2. High enough that the medicine is expected�to be profitable for the manufacturer

22 of 71

CLASS DISCUSSION

1. Do you agree with this initial definition�of a ‘fair’ price for a medicine?

2. Are there any other considerations that�you think should be taken into account?

23 of 71

STEP 1:

PRICING MEDICINES INDEPENDENTLY

24 of 71

ASSUMPTIONS

A publicly funded health care payer perspective is adopted, consistent with the reference case used by numerous health technology assessment (HTA) agencies internationally

Given this perspective, the objective of the payer is to�improve population health outcomes

The implications of adopting a broader perspective, or a different objective, are considered later in the paper

25 of 71

ASSUMPTIONS

Medicines have a single indication, and patients are homogenous, such that the incremental benefit of the medicine increases in proportion to the quantity supplied

Medicines have marginal net budget impact,�which falls upon a single constrained budget

The implications of multiple indications, or non-marginal budget impact, are considered later in the paper

26 of 71

ASSUMPTIONS

Manufacturers incur substantial costs of production�and will not supply to the health system at a loss

There is a single minimum price at which a medicine’s manufacturer is willing to supply to the health care system�in question, hereafter referred to as the reserve price

The reserve price implies a corresponding reserve ICER�(i.e. the medicine’s ICER when priced at its reserve price)

27 of 71

ASSUMPTIONS

Manufacturers of new medicines are protected from competition by a time-limited patent monopoly

This allows manufacturers to raise prices above those�required to cover marginal costs of production

The time-limited nature of patent protection raises dynamic considerations that are considered later in the paper

28 of 71

THE DEMAND CURVE

The demand curve plots the highest price that the payer would be willing to pay for any given quantity of medicine

Given an objective of improving population health, the demand curve is plotted at the price at which there is no population health impact from reimbursing the medicine

At this price, the ICER equals the marginal cost of producing a unit of health (k) within the health system in question

29 of 71

30 of 71

31 of 71

EMPIRICAL ESTIMATES OF THE MARGINAL COST OF HEALTH PRODUCED BY�A HEALTHCARE SYSTEM: METHODOLOGICAL CONSIDERATIONS FROM COUNTRY-LEVEL ESTIMATES

Edney LC, Lomas J, Karnon J, Vallejo-Torres L, Stadhouders N, Siverskog J, et al.

Pharmacoeconomics. 2022;40:31–43

doi.org/10.1007/s40273-021-01087-6

32 of 71

England�(University of York)

£12,936 per QALY (2008 GBP)

33 of 71

England�(University of York)

£12,936 per QALY (2008 GBP)

Spain�(University of Las Palmas de Gran Canaria)

€24,870 per QALY (2012 EUR)

34 of 71

England�(University of York)

£12,936 per QALY (2008 GBP)

Spain�(University of Las Palmas de Gran Canaria)

€24,870 per QALY (2012 EUR)

Australia�(University of Adelaide)

$28,033 per QALY (2012 AUD)

35 of 71

England�(University of York)

£12,936 per QALY (2008 GBP)

Spain�(University of Las Palmas de Gran Canaria)

€24,870 per QALY (2012 EUR)

Australia�(University of Adelaide)

$28,033 per QALY (2012 AUD)

Sweden�(Linköping University)

183,539 kr per QALY (2016 SEK)

36 of 71

Original�Estimate1

£12,936(2008 GBP)

$27,172(Converted to 2019 CAD)

Original�Estimate2

€24,870(2012 EUR)

$49,143(Converted to 2019 CAD)

Original�Estimate3

$28,033(2012 AUD)

$30,628(Converted to 2019 CAD)

Original�Estimate4

183,539 kr(2016 SEK)

$26,948(Converted to 2019 CAD)

All are below�$50,000 per QALY�(2019 CAD)

Median around�$30,000 per QALY�(2019 CAD)

References

1. Claxton et al. (2015)

2. Vallejo‐Torres et al. (2018)

3. Edney et al. (2018)

4. Siverskog & Henriksson (2019)

37 of 71

CLASS DISCUSSION

Suppose the marginal cost of producing a QALY within�the health care system in question is $30,000

What would be the direction of impact on population health�(gain, loss, or no effect) of reimbursing a medicine that costs:

(a) $15,000 per QALY?

(b) $30,000 per QALY?

(c) $60,000 per QALY?

38 of 71

THE SUPPLY CURVE

The supply curve plots the lowest price that a manufacturer would be willing to accept when supplying any quantity of medicine to the health care system in question

Plotting the supply curve is challenging: it is a function of many factors, including marginal costs of production and�the implications of reference pricing in other jurisdictions�(a manufacturer may not accept an otherwise profitable�price if it results in a lower price in other jurisdictions)

39 of 71

KEY RESULT

In general, there is a range of possible ‘fair’ prices at�which consumer and producer surplus are both positive

The upper bound of this range is a price corresponding�to the demand curve, such that the ICER equals k and�there is no population health gain (consumer surplus)

The lower bound is determined by the supply curve, where there is no return to the manufacturer (producer surplus)

40 of 71

41 of 71

STEP 2:

PRICING MEDICINES COLLECTIVELY

42 of 71

ASSUMPTIONS

A maximum ‘common price’ for a unit of health (λ), or�cost-effectiveness ‘threshold’, is specified by the payer

Medicines with a reserve ICER less than or equal to λ are supplied and strategically priced so that the ICER equals λ

In practice, this can arise from manufacturers ‘pricing up’ to λ,�or setting a higher initial price and negotiating down to λ,�or through ‘value-based pricing’ that explicitly prices at λ

43 of 71

EXAMPLE

The marginal cost of producing a QALY (k) is £15,000

The marginal value of a QALY (v) is £30,000 or £60,000

Medicine

Health Gain (QALYs)

Reserve ICER (per QALY)

A

30

£2,750

B

60

£7,750

C

45

£12,250

D

45

£19,250

44 of 71

45 of 71

46 of 71

47 of 71

48 of 71

49 of 71

50 of 71

51 of 71

52 of 71

53 of 71

RETURN ON INVESTMENT

54 of 71

MANUFACTURER

A limitation with the supply curve (and producer surplus) is that it does not consider fixed costs, including R&D costs

Manufacturers incur substantial costs and risks when developing new medicines - they also incur the costs of�medicines that fail during clinical trials

Furthermore, investing capital in developing medicines has an opportunity cost, since it could generate returns elsewhere

55 of 71

MANUFACTURER

The definition of a ‘fair’ price can be refined to address this

The manufacturer should be allocated a sufficient share of the total welfare to cover fixed costs (including R&D), and enough surplus to reward the risk taken in developing the medicine

This is particularly important for drugs with small target populations, for which development costs must be recovered from fewer patients, and for which R&D may be riskier

56 of 71

PAYER

The payer also takes risks when reimbursing medicines

Both the health gains and health losses are uncertain -�as a result, there can be substantial uncertainty as to the net impact of reimbursing a medicine upon population health

Reimbursing a medicine should therefore be�considered as a risky investment by the payer

57 of 71

PAYER

Since the broad purpose of a public health care system�is to improve the health of the public, the return on this investment may be considered in terms of population health�(instead of monetary terms)

A pharmacoeconomic model may be used to estimate�the health gains and losses, discounted to a present value,�with probabilistic analysis used to consider the payer’s risk -�the payer’s return should be commensurate with this risk

58 of 71

PAYER

The definition of a ‘fair’ price can be refined to reflect this

The payer should be allocated enough economic surplus to cover its fixed costs, and enough additional surplus to reward the risk taken in reimbursing the medicine

In other words, a ‘fair’ price is one at which the consumer surplus is sufficiently positive to provide the payer with a reasonable rate of return on its investment

59 of 71

A SINGLE ‘FAIR’ PRICE

A fundamental principle of financial economics is that a risky investment requires a positive expected rate of return, with�a greater risk requiring a greater expected rate of return

A potential approach to specifying a single ‘fair’ price is to equalize the risk-adjusted rates of return for both the manufacturer and payer, resulting in a greater nominal�return for the party that incurs greater risk

60 of 71

A SINGLE ‘FAIR’ PRICE

For example, if the manufacturer incurs a greater risk�in developing the medicine than the payer incurs in�reimbursing the medicine, then a greater proportion of the economic surplus would be allocated to the manufacturer

This approach would reward manufacturers who come�to market with higher quality evidence, since this�would reduce the risks faced by the payer

61 of 71

DYNAMIC PRICING

In practice, a complicating factor is that a medicine is�unlikely to have just one price over its lifecycle

For example, the price of a medicine may be expected to fall after patent expiry, when it is subject to generic competition

It follows that a ‘fair’ price (or ‘fair’ set of prices, if prices change over time) should, as far as practicable, be established over the entire lifecycle of the medicine

62 of 71

FURTHER CONSIDERATIONS

63 of 71

MEDICINES WITH�NO ‘’FAIR PRICE

For medicines that have relatively high marginal costs of production and/or provide relatively small incremental benefits to patients, it is possible that the supply curve�lies above the demand curve

In such cases there are no ‘fair’ prices at which both�consumer and producer surplus are positive,�since the total economic surplus is negative

64 of 71

RELAXING THE ASSUMPTIONS

The paper considers what happens when we relax many�of the assumptions made earlier, by considering:

  • Multiple Indications and Heterogeneity
  • Non-Marginal Net Budget Impact
  • Multiple Budgets or Budgetary Silos
  • A Societal Perspective and/or Equity Weighting
  • The Dynamic Impact of Innovation

65 of 71

SUMMARY

66 of 71

SUMMARY

A framework has been proposed to support the determination of ‘fair’ prices for medicines

The framework attempts to strike a balance between the interests of patients and the interests of manufacturers

The framework makes three departures from convention, with important implications for the ‘fair’ pricing of medicines

67 of 71

SUMMARY

1. The proposed framework does not consider k and v as competing approaches for defining a common price�for a unit of health (or cost-effectiveness ‘threshold’)

Instead, k is a component of a medicine’s demand curve, allowing for estimation of the consumer surplus at any price

Meanwhile v is used to value the consumer surplus in monetary terms to allow for calculation of the total welfare

68 of 71

SUMMARY

2. The framework assumes a relationship between the common price offered by the payer and the resulting�ICERs of medicines (i.e. ‘pricing to the threshold’)

When medicines are priced collectively, the payer must�take this strategic pricing behaviour into account

Total welfare is maximized at a common price below k, with consumer surplus maximized at an even lower common price

69 of 71

SUMMARY

3. The framework recognizes that reimbursing medicines�is a risky investment by the payer, given the often substantial uncertainty regarding the expected�impact on net population health outcomes

Conventionally, research on ‘return on investment’ has�focused only on the manufacturer; under this framework,�ensuring a ‘fair’ price requires that these considerations�be extended to the payer

70 of 71

CLASS DISCUSSION

What are the implications of this framework for payers?

What are the implications for manufacturers?

Do you have any further thoughts about how a ‘fair’�price might be established for a medicine?

71 of 71

WANT TO LEARN MORE?

Download these slides from

fairpricing.mikepaulden.org

or by scanning this QR code

Visit mikepaulden.org today