1 of 143

Pricing in Designed Markets:

The Case of Ride-Sharing

Jonathan Hall

Uber Technologies

John Horton

MIT & NBER

Dan Knoepfle

Uber Technologies

2 of 143

The “sharing" or "gig" economy

2

Banking

Food

Hotels

Real Estate

Retailing

Healthcare

Transportation

Diversified Labor

Personal Services

Corporate Services

Rental Cars

3 of 143

To what extent do platform markets

"set" prices on their platforms?

4 of 143

The choice of price structure

  • Platform takes a percentage of transactions; supply side takes the rest
  • Some platforms set the price faced by buyers
    • Seems sensible, but the comparative statics for a price change are puzzling

5 of 143

Suppose Uber cuts fares in a city by 20%.

Passengers demand more trips

But drivers now make less per trip, and presumably want to supply fewer

How is the "gap" closed?

6 of 143

This talk

  • Show how the "gap" is closed
  • Discuss the economic implications of the market adjustment process

7 of 143

Driver paystub from a week of working

8 of 143

Drivers gross hourly earnings rate

w = $11.30/hour gross earnings rate

9 of 143

Hours of work are transformed into hours of transportation services

(assuming US avg. trip duration)

~16 hours of transportation

10 of 143

Fraction of hours-worked that are "on trip" is "utilization" or technical labor productivity

"Utilization" = x =

11 of 143

Flow of money earned while on a trip

12 of 143

Driver hourly earnings rate decomposed

Flow of $ while on a trip

Fraction of hours- worked on trip (utilization)

*

w =

*

Base fare "flow"

Surge multiplier

Flow of $ while on a trip

=

13 of 143

The supply of driver hours-worked

H(w)

Hours

Hours online

w

14 of 143

The transformation of hours-worked into hours of transportation services: hours scaled by utilization

x H(w)

Hours

H(w)

Hours of driving with passengers

w

15 of 143

Key point: Utilization

changes shift the

product market supply curve

16 of 143

Demand for hours of transportation services

Hours

D(p)

Price /

Hour Transportation

p

17 of 143

A market equilibrium: Hours demand = hours supplied

x H(w)

Hours

D(p)

Price /

Hour Transportation

Driver earnings rate / Hour Worked

Equilibrium quantity of hours of transportation

p

px

18 of 143

Suppose prices are lowered

19 of 143

Fare cut

x H(w)

Hours

Prices

D(p)

1. Uber decreases fare by dp.

p

w

20 of 143

Gap, before the market adjusts

x H(w)

Hours

Prices

D(p)

2. Hourly earnings rate falls by dp x

p

w

"gap"

21 of 143

Paths to a new equilibrium after a fare increase

  • Both passengers and drivers are completely inelastic
  • Drivers have a downward sloping labor supply curve
  • Changes in surge pricing essentially "undo" a fare change
  • Service quality deteriorates, shifting in the demand curve
  • Increase in driver technical productivity i.e., increase in utilization

22 of 143

Paths to a new equilibrium after a fare increase

  • Both passengers and drivers are completely inelastic
  • Drivers have a downward sloping labor supply curve
  • Changes in surge pricing essentially "undo" a fare change
    • Yes, in part
  • Service quality deteriorates, shifting in the demand curve
    • Yes, in part
  • Increase in driver technical productivity i.e., increase in utilization
    • Yes, in part

Results preview

23 of 143

Empirics

24 of 143

25 of 143

N = 43 US Cities with UberX

T = Weeks from

June 2014 to Jan 2017

26 of 143

xit

UberX price index in city i in week t

yit

Average outcome in city i in week t

Price Index: Price of a 6 mile, 16 minute unsurged trip that week, in that city.

27 of 143

xit

UberX price index in city i in week t

yit

Average outcome in city i in week t

Price Index: Price of a 6 mile, 16 minute unsurged trip that week, in that city.

E.g.,

t = 3/6/2016 - 3/12/2016

i = New York City

xit , Trip Price Index = $24.04

yit , Hourly earnings rate = $34.00

28 of 143

Price variation

29 of 143

Fare goes up

Fare does down

(seemingly not touted)

30 of 143

E.g., NYC had a 13% decrease and a 6% decrease

31 of 143

Some changes coordinated across cities

32 of 143

Small between-city differences in the precise week of a change

33 of 143

Between-city variation in size of the change.

34 of 143

Distribution of fare changes

35 of 143

City-week grand means over time

36 of 143

Base trip price index

Long-run decline in fares

Jan. fare decreases "show up" clearly

37 of 143

But little evidence of sustained higher surge

Surge

Surge rises following Jan. fare decrease

38 of 143

Large increases in utilization

Utilization

Increases in utilization around Jan. fare cuts; seem ~ persistent

39 of 143

No persistent changes in the hourly earnings rate

Hourly earnings rate

Dip following fare cuts, then increase

40 of 143

Identification

41 of 143

Leaks about Uber decision-making on pricing

42 of 143

City-specific changes in the base fare

  • Random?
    • No - Uber has a team that works on pricing.
    • But they seem to have been selecting on "observables"
    • Little evidence of forecasting
  • Double fixed effects panel (with unit specific time trend) can "handle" selection on observables
    • 2021 Update: Who knows what TWFE with continuous treatment does anymore...
  • No evidence results are sensitive to city-specific weather, unemployment rate, competitors, etc. - See paper
  • The pattern of variation in fare changes looks promising
    • E.g., all are "treated," small timing differences, etc.
  • Highly granular data makes parallel trends assumption assessable

43 of 143

Regression approach

44 of 143

The "long-run" specification

Outcome of interest in city i at week t.

Base price index at city i at week t.

City i specific effect

Week t specific effect

City i specific time trend

45 of 143

Base fare index (log) in that particular city & week

46 of 143

10% fare increase reduces avg. surge multiplier by 2%

47 of 143

10% fare increase reduces utilization/tech. productivity by 7%

48 of 143

Positive but small effect on the gross hourly earnings rate.

49 of 143

Accounting for the adjustment process

50 of 143

Showing the dynamics

Main specification: 15 pre, 25 post (see paper for alt. leads/lags)

51 of 143

Surge multiplier

52 of 143

Surge multiplier

No evidence of pre-period pre-trends

53 of 143

Surge multiplier

Gradual decline in surge following a fare increase (~30% by end of the period)

54 of 143

Utilization

55 of 143

Utilization

8% reduction in utilization following a 10% fare increase by week 8; close to 10% near end.

56 of 143

Hourly earnings rate

57 of 143

Hourly earnings rate

Initial pass-through, then steady decline, turning negative by week 8.

58 of 143

Other outcomes related to

market clearing

59 of 143

"D"

"w"

"x"

Surge multiplier (changes in "p")

"H"

Wait-times (related to φ(x))

60 of 143

# trips and hours with passengers decline with higher prices

61 of 143

Driver compensation effects are sensitive to definition, but mostly positive

62 of 143

Clear decline in driver technical productivity with higher prices

63 of 143

Surge goes down, frac. of earnings from promotions goes down; no change in market share

64 of 143

Driver hours-worked increases with higher fares; effect seems to be on the intensive margin

65 of 143

Wait-times clearly increase; some evidence that trips get shorter

66 of 143

Back to the simple model

67 of 143

x S(w)

Hours

Prices

D(p)

p

w

68 of 143

Adjustment: Some increase in surge offsets dp

x S(w)

Hours

Prices

D(p)

p

w

69 of 143

Adjustment: Increase in wait-times (demand shift)

x S(w)

Hours

Prices

D(p)

p

w

D2(p)

70 of 143

Adjustment: Increase in utilization

x S(w)

Hours

Prices

D(p)

p

w

D2(p)

x2 S(px2)

Utilization works on supply curve two ways: "inside" (more hours) & "outside" (more productive)

71 of 143

Implications

72 of 143

What we know from the emprics

  • There is clearly a price/utilization trade-off at the market level
  • There is clearly a utilization/wait-time trade-off at the market level
  • Some of the base price changes are "undone" by surge
  • Welfare effects of fare increases are ambiguous for drivers but probably negative, at least on average
    • Fare increases seem to lower hourly earnings rates, but the increase in hours-worked suggest they are better-off overall

73 of 143

Who gains and loses?

74 of 143

Market clearing condition: hours demanded is hours supplied

Disutility from Passenger wait-time

Driver net hourly earnings rate

This price can reflect platform surge changes

75 of 143

x-axis axis: Driver Utilization

76 of 143

x-axis axis: Driver Utilization

y-axis: Price

77 of 143

Drivers want really

high prices & high utilization

($$$)

78 of 143

y-axis: Price

x-axis axis: Driver Utilization

Driver Happy Place

79 of 143

Passengers want really

low prices & low utilization

(cheap & short wait-times)

80 of 143

y-axis: Price

x-axis axis: Driver Utilization

Driver Happy Place

Pax

Happy Place

81 of 143

But only some of these price/utilization combinations are equally equilibriums

82 of 143

y-axis: Price

x-axis axis: Driver Utilization

Driver Happy Place

Pax

Happy Place

Possible (p, x)

Equilibria

83 of 143

Which one do drivers like?

84 of 143

y-axis: Price

x-axis axis: Driver Utilization

Driver Happy Place

Pax

Happy Place

Drive indifference curve

85 of 143

Which one do passengers like?

86 of 143

y-axis: Price

x-axis axis: Driver Utilization

Driver Happy Place

Pax

Happy Place

Pax

indifference curve

87 of 143

Making both groups happy is a knife-edge condition

88 of 143

Driver-preferred equilibrium

Pax-preferred

equilibrium

89 of 143

But both sides can agree about what to do about prices in certain conditions. E.g., prices are too high:

90 of 143

Both sides want fare cuts

91 of 143

Or prices are too low:

92 of 143

Both sides want fare

increases

93 of 143

But in a range, both sides are implaccable

94 of 143

Drivers want fare increases; Passengers want fare cuts

95 of 143

Thank you

John Horton http://john-joseph-horton.com/

@johnjhorton

96 of 143

Backup slides

97 of 143

Driver labor

98 of 143

Hours-worked per driver

Driver churn

More hours-worked / less exit when hourly earnings rate is higher

99 of 143

Hours-worked per driver

Driver churn

But it persists once hourly wage effect has turned negative.

100 of 143

Why more hours-worked when hourly earnings are lower? Answer: Utilization is costly to drivers.

With lower utilization, less fuel expenditure; less wear and tear.

Not captured: greater effort; short breaks have a higher opportunity cost

101 of 143

Service quality (wait-times)

102 of 143

Median wait time from dispatch to pick-up

With a higher fare/lower utilization, nearest available care is close and so wait-times fall

103 of 143

Market quantities

104 of 143

Much less precise, but clear evidence of utilization trade-off: More hours-worked but fewer hours with customers

105 of 143

Thoughts on welfare

106 of 143

Effect of a fare cut

(ignoring wait-times)

107 of 143

Social planner wants to increase this area as much as possible

108 of 143

Gap between supply and demand versus utilization

109 of 143

Accounting for costs

110 of 143

Costs depend in part on mileage

At $0.54/mile and 6 mile avg. trip, expenses ~$185

111 of 143

Costs per hour of driving depends on the city and utilization

Speed when w/ passengers

Speed when not with passengers

112 of 143

Log hourly costs

net

gross

Log hourly earnings

113 of 143

Implications of endogenous

technical productivity

114 of 143

x, utilization

w, wage

Driver indifference curve

115 of 143

x, utilization

w, wage

More hours

Fewer hours

116 of 143

Satisfying a fixed

amount of demand, D(p)

117 of 143

x, utilization

w, wage

Fewer hours-worked,

high utilization

Many hours-worked, lower utilization

118 of 143

What if there is a lower

product market price?

119 of 143

x, utilization

w, wage

Ways to meet demand with a lower product market price

Higher utilization

More

hours

Possibilities with p = pH

Possibilities with p = pL

120 of 143

Which hours/utilization combo have drivers earning MRP (w = px)

(i.e., could be equilibria)?

121 of 143

x, utilization

w, wage

Low price equilibrium in which drivers get MRP

High price equilibrium in which drivers get MRP

Slope = pL

Slope = pH

x(pL )

x(pH )

122 of 143

Many possible equilibria with depending on the product market price set by the platform

123 of 143

x, utilization

w, wage

A = High price, low utilization

equilibrium

B = Low price, high utilization equilibrium

A

B

124 of 143

What equilibria should "we" prefer?

125 of 143

Consider small changes in utilization, dx

x, utilization

w, wage

Value of more output greater than the cost to worker, or:

p dx > w

126 of 143

Consider small changes in utilization

x, utilization

w, wage

Value of more output greater than the cost to worker, or:

p dx > w

Value of more output less than the cost to the worker, or:

p dx < w

127 of 143

x, utilization

w, wage

Value of more output = cost to worker

128 of 143

Should we expect the decentralized efficient price?

Long-history of taxi regulation---and relatively unsuccessful de-regulation attempts in 70s and 80s.

By centralizing pricing, are ride-sharing platforms solving the "Diamond (1971)" problem?

129 of 143

Thank you

Authors: Jonathan Hall, John Horton and Dan Knoepfle

Link: http://www.john-joseph-horton.com/papers/uber_price.pdf

130 of 143

Backup Slides

131 of 143

Promotional payments (e.g., earnings guarantees)

Hourly earnings without promotions

Hourly earnings with promotions

Greater pass through of fare changes without promotional payments included

132 of 143

Alternative within-city approach

  • Basic idea: Compare UberX/UberBlack within the same city
  • Advantages:
    • Alleviates some of the concern about city-specific selection
    • City-specific shocks (concerts, sports, very localized weather etc.) are netted out
  • Disadvantages
    • UberX and UberBlack compete with each other
    • In many cities, UberBlack drivers can take UberX requests

133 of 143

134 of 143

Some implications of the market quantity results

  • Reduction in trips means price effect outweighs the quality effect
  • Change in hours-worked is an intensive margin rather than extensive margin effect
  • Long-run hours-worked change despite no change in hourly earnings rate, consistent with highly elastic labor supply to Uber

135 of 143

Uber taking prices was not ex ante obvious

  • Factors suggesting inelastic supply:
    • Unique flexible work option
    • Some past evidence of target earning by drivers
    • Regulatory/capital barriers to entry are not zero
  • Factors suggesting elastic supply:
    • Drivers have complete flexibility of hours-worked
    • Barriers to entry are not that high
    • Existence of competitor platforms allow driver to easily switch

136 of 143

137 of 143

Related literature

  • Spillover effects of the introduction of Uber on:
  • Preferences and welfare of riders and drivers
    • Value of flexibility to drivers (Chen et al)
    • Racial discrimination (Ge et al.)
    • Price sensitivity of riders (Cohen et al.)
    • Labor supply elasticity of drivers (Chen & Shelden)
  • Descriptive
    • Who Uber drivers are & what do they want (Hall & Krueger)
    • Gig economy labor (Katz & Krueger)
    • How does the market "work"? (this paper)

138 of 143

Conceptual framework assumptions

  • Riders face a fare that has (1) fixed fee and (2) a variable component based on time and distance
    • For simplicity, we are going to assume riders buy hours of transportation at a price, p.
  • Drivers are paid a % of the gross receipts
    • For now, I'm going to assume Uber's take is 0%.
    • I'm going to ignore cost of gas, wear and tear, miscellaneous costs, and so on.
  • Role of surge pricing:
    • By assumption, it "works" to keep wait times more or less constant (hence keeping the demand curve fixed).
    • It is applied as a multiplier, m to the base fare rate, b, and so p = bm.
  • Demand curves slope down, supply curves slope up

139 of 143

Robustness check - can synthetic control approach work for previous outcomes?

Same pattern of results: no long-run change in hourly earnings because of changes to utilization & surge

140 of 143

# of trips

#

hours-worked

# drivers working

141 of 143

Fare increase leads to a reduction in the number of trips taken

142 of 143

Fare increase has seemingly no effect on the number of active drivers

143 of 143

Fare increase leads to a reduction hours