Pricing in Designed Markets:
The Case of Ride-Sharing
Jonathan Hall
Uber Technologies
John Horton
MIT & NBER
Dan Knoepfle
Uber Technologies
The “sharing" or "gig" economy
2
Banking
Food
Hotels
Real Estate
Retailing
Healthcare
Transportation
Diversified Labor
Personal Services
Corporate Services
Rental Cars
To what extent do platform markets
"set" prices on their platforms?
The choice of price structure
Suppose Uber cuts fares in a city by 20%.
Passengers demand more trips
But drivers now make less per trip, and presumably want to supply fewer
How is the "gap" closed?
This talk
Driver paystub from a week of working
Drivers gross hourly earnings rate
w = $11.30/hour gross earnings rate
Hours of work are transformed into hours of transportation services
(assuming US avg. trip duration)
~16 hours of transportation
Fraction of hours-worked that are "on trip" is "utilization" or technical labor productivity
"Utilization" = x =
Flow of money earned while on a trip
Driver hourly earnings rate decomposed
Flow of $ while on a trip
Fraction of hours- worked on trip (utilization)
*
w =
*
Base fare "flow"
Surge multiplier
Flow of $ while on a trip
=
The supply of driver hours-worked
H(w)
Hours
Hours online
w
The transformation of hours-worked into hours of transportation services: hours scaled by utilization
x H(w)
Hours
H(w)
Hours of driving with passengers
w
Key point: Utilization
changes shift the
product market supply curve
Demand for hours of transportation services
Hours
D(p)
Price /
Hour Transportation
p
A market equilibrium: Hours demand = hours supplied
x H(w)
Hours
D(p)
Price /
Hour Transportation
Driver earnings rate / Hour Worked
Equilibrium quantity of hours of transportation
p
px
Suppose prices are lowered
Fare cut
x H(w)
Hours
Prices
D(p)
1. Uber decreases fare by dp.
p
w
Gap, before the market adjusts
x H(w)
Hours
Prices
D(p)
2. Hourly earnings rate falls by dp x
p
w
"gap"
Paths to a new equilibrium after a fare increase
Paths to a new equilibrium after a fare increase
Results preview
Empirics
N = 43 US Cities with UberX
T = Weeks from
June 2014 to Jan 2017
xit
UberX price index in city i in week t
yit
Average outcome in city i in week t
Price Index: Price of a 6 mile, 16 minute unsurged trip that week, in that city.
xit
UberX price index in city i in week t
yit
Average outcome in city i in week t
Price Index: Price of a 6 mile, 16 minute unsurged trip that week, in that city.
E.g.,
t = 3/6/2016 - 3/12/2016
i = New York City
xit , Trip Price Index = $24.04
yit , Hourly earnings rate = $34.00
Price variation
Fare goes up
Fare does down
(seemingly not touted)
E.g., NYC had a 13% decrease and a 6% decrease
Some changes coordinated across cities
Small between-city differences in the precise week of a change
Between-city variation in size of the change.
Distribution of fare changes
City-week grand means over time
Base trip price index
Long-run decline in fares
Jan. fare decreases "show up" clearly
But little evidence of sustained higher surge
Surge
Surge rises following Jan. fare decrease
Large increases in utilization
Utilization
Increases in utilization around Jan. fare cuts; seem ~ persistent
No persistent changes in the hourly earnings rate
Hourly earnings rate
Dip following fare cuts, then increase
Identification
Leaks about Uber decision-making on pricing
City-specific changes in the base fare
Regression approach
The "long-run" specification
Outcome of interest in city i at week t.
Base price index at city i at week t.
City i specific effect
Week t specific effect
City i specific time trend
Base fare index (log) in that particular city & week
10% fare increase reduces avg. surge multiplier by 2%
10% fare increase reduces utilization/tech. productivity by 7%
Positive but small effect on the gross hourly earnings rate.
Accounting for the adjustment process
Showing the dynamics
Main specification: 15 pre, 25 post (see paper for alt. leads/lags)
Surge multiplier
Surge multiplier
No evidence of pre-period pre-trends
Surge multiplier
Gradual decline in surge following a fare increase (~30% by end of the period)
Utilization
Utilization
8% reduction in utilization following a 10% fare increase by week 8; close to 10% near end.
Hourly earnings rate
Hourly earnings rate
Initial pass-through, then steady decline, turning negative by week 8.
Other outcomes related to
market clearing
"D"
"w"
"x"
Surge multiplier (changes in "p")
"H"
Wait-times (related to φ(x))
# trips and hours with passengers decline with higher prices
Driver compensation effects are sensitive to definition, but mostly positive
Clear decline in driver technical productivity with higher prices
Surge goes down, frac. of earnings from promotions goes down; no change in market share
Driver hours-worked increases with higher fares; effect seems to be on the intensive margin
Wait-times clearly increase; some evidence that trips get shorter
Back to the simple model
x S(w)
Hours
Prices
D(p)
p
w
Adjustment: Some increase in surge offsets dp
x S(w)
Hours
Prices
D(p)
p
w
Adjustment: Increase in wait-times (demand shift)
x S(w)
Hours
Prices
D(p)
p
w
D2(p)
Adjustment: Increase in utilization
x S(w)
Hours
Prices
D(p)
p
w
D2(p)
x2 S(px2)
Utilization works on supply curve two ways: "inside" (more hours) & "outside" (more productive)
Implications
What we know from the emprics
Who gains and loses?
Market clearing condition: hours demanded is hours supplied
Disutility from Passenger wait-time
Driver net hourly earnings rate
This price can reflect platform surge changes
x-axis axis: Driver Utilization
x-axis axis: Driver Utilization
y-axis: Price
Drivers want really
high prices & high utilization
($$$)
y-axis: Price
x-axis axis: Driver Utilization
Driver Happy Place
Passengers want really
low prices & low utilization
(cheap & short wait-times)
y-axis: Price
x-axis axis: Driver Utilization
Driver Happy Place
Pax
Happy Place
But only some of these price/utilization combinations are equally equilibriums
y-axis: Price
x-axis axis: Driver Utilization
Driver Happy Place
Pax
Happy Place
Possible (p, x)
Equilibria
Which one do drivers like?
y-axis: Price
x-axis axis: Driver Utilization
Driver Happy Place
Pax
Happy Place
Drive indifference curve
Which one do passengers like?
y-axis: Price
x-axis axis: Driver Utilization
Driver Happy Place
Pax
Happy Place
Pax
indifference curve
Making both groups happy is a knife-edge condition
Driver-preferred equilibrium
Pax-preferred
equilibrium
But both sides can agree about what to do about prices in certain conditions. E.g., prices are too high:
Both sides want fare cuts
Or prices are too low:
Both sides want fare
increases
But in a range, both sides are implaccable
Drivers want fare increases; Passengers want fare cuts
Thank you
John Horton http://john-joseph-horton.com/
@johnjhorton
Backup slides
Driver labor
Hours-worked per driver
Driver churn
More hours-worked / less exit when hourly earnings rate is higher
Hours-worked per driver
Driver churn
But it persists once hourly wage effect has turned negative.
Why more hours-worked when hourly earnings are lower? Answer: Utilization is costly to drivers.
With lower utilization, less fuel expenditure; less wear and tear.
Not captured: greater effort; short breaks have a higher opportunity cost
Service quality (wait-times)
Median wait time from dispatch to pick-up
With a higher fare/lower utilization, nearest available care is close and so wait-times fall
Market quantities
Much less precise, but clear evidence of utilization trade-off: More hours-worked but fewer hours with customers
Thoughts on welfare
Effect of a fare cut
(ignoring wait-times)
Social planner wants to increase this area as much as possible
Gap between supply and demand versus utilization
Accounting for costs
Costs depend in part on mileage
At $0.54/mile and 6 mile avg. trip, expenses ~$185
Costs per hour of driving depends on the city and utilization
Speed when w/ passengers
Speed when not with passengers
Log hourly costs
net
gross
Log hourly earnings
Implications of endogenous
technical productivity
x, utilization
w, wage
Driver indifference curve
x, utilization
w, wage
More hours
Fewer hours
Satisfying a fixed
amount of demand, D(p)
x, utilization
w, wage
Fewer hours-worked,
high utilization
Many hours-worked, lower utilization
What if there is a lower
product market price?
x, utilization
w, wage
Ways to meet demand with a lower product market price
Higher utilization
More
hours
Possibilities with p = pH
Possibilities with p = pL
Which hours/utilization combo have drivers earning MRP (w = px)
(i.e., could be equilibria)?
x, utilization
w, wage
Low price equilibrium in which drivers get MRP
High price equilibrium in which drivers get MRP
Slope = pL
Slope = pH
x(pL )
x(pH )
Many possible equilibria with depending on the product market price set by the platform
x, utilization
w, wage
A = High price, low utilization
equilibrium
B = Low price, high utilization equilibrium
A
B
What equilibria should "we" prefer?
Consider small changes in utilization, dx
x, utilization
w, wage
Value of more output greater than the cost to worker, or:
p dx > w
Consider small changes in utilization
x, utilization
w, wage
Value of more output greater than the cost to worker, or:
p dx > w
Value of more output less than the cost to the worker, or:
p dx < w
x, utilization
w, wage
Value of more output = cost to worker
Should we expect the decentralized efficient price?
Long-history of taxi regulation---and relatively unsuccessful de-regulation attempts in 70s and 80s.
By centralizing pricing, are ride-sharing platforms solving the "Diamond (1971)" problem?
Thank you
Authors: Jonathan Hall, John Horton and Dan Knoepfle
Link: http://www.john-joseph-horton.com/papers/uber_price.pdf
Backup Slides
Promotional payments (e.g., earnings guarantees)
Hourly earnings without promotions
Hourly earnings with promotions
Greater pass through of fare changes without promotional payments included
Alternative within-city approach
Some implications of the market quantity results
Uber taking prices was not ex ante obvious
Related literature
Conceptual framework assumptions
Robustness check - can synthetic control approach work for previous outcomes?
Same pattern of results: no long-run change in hourly earnings because of changes to utilization & surge
# of trips
#
hours-worked
# drivers working
Fare increase leads to a reduction in the number of trips taken
Fare increase has seemingly no effect on the number of active drivers
Fare increase leads to a reduction hours