Page 1 of 50
Demand Shocks as Productivity Shocks∗
Yan Bai
University of Rochester
Jos ́e-V ́ıctor R ́ıos-Rull
University of Minnesota, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, CAERP, CEPR, and NBER
Kjetil Storesletten
University of Oslo, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, and CEPR
∗We thank seminar attendants at the University of Pennsylvania, New York University, Bank of Canada, European
Central Bank, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Institute for Fiscal Studies,
Toulouse University, and CREI-CEPR for useful comments. We are especially thankful to Gary Hansen, Ellen
McGrattan, and Larry Christiano. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System.
1
Page 2 of 50
Abstract
We provide a macroeconomic model where demand for goods has a productive role. A
search friction prevents perfect matching between potential customers and producers, and
larger demand induces more search, which in turn increases output in the economy. Con- sequently, when viewed through the lens of a standard neoclassical aggregate production
function, an increase in demand will appear as an increase in the Solow residual. We esti- mate the model using standard Bayesian techniques, allowing for business cycles being driven
by both preference shocks – which we interpret as shocks to demand – and true technology
shocks. Technology shocks account for less than 18% of the fluctuations in output and the
measured Solow residual. Our model also provides a novel theory for important macroeco- nomic variables such as the relative price of consumption and investment, Tobin’s Q, and
capacity utilization.
2
Page 3 of 50
1 Introduction
In the standard neoclassical model, output is a function of inputs such as labor and capital. There
is no explicit role for demand because (Walrasian) prices will adjust so that all produced goods
will be utilized. In reality, customers and producers must meet in order for the produced good to
be consumed, so value added depends on how well they are matched. As an example, consider
a restaurant. According to neoclassical theory, the output of a restaurant should be a function
of its employees, buildings, tables, and raw material, irrespective of market conditions. However,
the restaurant’s production takes place only when customers show up to buy meals. The more
customers who demand the restaurant’s meals, the more will be served and the larger the value
added will be. Thus, the demand for goods plays a direct role. The spirit of this example extends
to many forms of production: dentists need patients, car dealers need shoppers, all producers need
buyers.
This paper provides a theory where search for goods – which we sometimes refer to as demand
– has a productive role. The starting point is that potential customers search for producers, and
a standard matching friction prevents standard market clearing, in the neoclassical sense that all
potential productive capacity translates into actual value added. Clearly, for households and firms,
the acquisition of goods is an active process that involves costs not measured in the National
Income and Product Accounts (NIPA). Technically, we resolve the search friction by building on
the competitive search model Moen (1997). Firms post prices and customers trade off good prices
versus congestion when searching for the goods: prices are higher for goods that are easier to find.
Allowing such an explicit role for demand has direct implications for business cycle analysis,
especially for our understanding of the driving factors of business cycles. A striking consequence
of the type of demand-driven business cycle model we propose is that changes in demand will
increase output even if inputs, and the intensity with which they are used, remain constant. If
viewed through the lens of a standard neoclassical aggregate production function that ignores
demand, an increase in demand would imply an increase in total factor productivity (TFP). Thus,
a preference shock that boosts consumption will also show up as a shock to the Solow residual.
This mechanism reverses the direction of causation relative to the neoclassical model: there, a true
technology shock would increase TFP which, in turn, would increase consumption and investment.
Interestingly, aggregate data for the United States suggest that it is factors influencing consumption
that drives TFP, rather than TFP driving consumption. In particular, aggregate consumption turns
3